Transit Legacy Cities

phila.jpg

Transit's greatest potential to attract drivers from cars is the work trip. But an analysis of US transit work trip destinations indicates that this applies in large part to   just a few destinations around the nation. This is much more obvious in looking at destinations than the more typical method of analysis, which looks at the residential locations of commuters. This column is adapted from my new Heritage Foundation Backgrounder "Transit Policy in an Era of the Shrinking Federal Dollar."

Transit Legacy Cities

Transit commuting is heavily concentrated to destinations in just the six core cities (historical core municipalities) of New York, Chicago, Philadelphia, San Francisco, Boston and Washington (Backgrounder Chart 9). I call them the "transit legacy cities," because their high transit market shares relate to their development before the automobile became dominant. Because there is such a lack of clarity in the use of terms that apply to cities, it is important to emphasize that the transit legacy cities are municipalities, not the surrounding metropolitan areas or urban areas, where the majority of residents live (Note 1). 


The transit legacy cities account for nearly 55 percent of the nation's transit commuters, by work trip destinations, according to the American Community Survey (2008-2010). By contrast, the transit legacy cities have an overall national employment market share barely one-tenth their national transit share (6 percent). Moreover, combined, the transit legacy cities cover a land area little larger than the core city (municipality) of Jacksonville, Florida.

At the same time, the "other side of the coin" is that commuting to other destinations is dominated by the automobile, from the suburbs in metropolitan areas with transit legacy cities, and even more so in the other 45 major metropolitan areas (with more than 1,000,000 population) and the balance of the nation.

Legacy Cities: Transit's Strength

The extent of the concentration in the six transit legacy cities is illustrated in Backgrounder Table 1. In some ways, transit is, first and foremost,  really a New York story. More than one-third of all transit work-trip commuting is to destinations in the core city of New York. The dominance is even greater for high-capacity subways/elevated services, a mode in which where New York represents two-thirds of national commuting.

The Key: Large, Concentrated, Well Served Downtowns: The concentration of transit commuting in the six transit legacy cities reflects the factor that is probably more responsible than any other for attracting people from cars to transit. This is a highly concentrated downtown area (central business district, or "CBD") from which a dense network of rapid transit services radiates.

The six transit legacy cities are also home to the six largest CBDs in the nation, where transit's share of commuting is far higher than compared to the rest of the nation. Approximately three quarters of commuters to the sprawling Manhattan CBD in New York (south of 59th Street) commuted by transit in 2000. Less well known is that New York also contains the CBD with the second largest transit work trip destination, downtown Brooklyn (58 percent), which is followed by downtown Chicago (55 percent).

In addition, between nearly 40 percent and more than 50 percent of commuters used transit to the CBDs of Boston, San Francisco, Philadelphia and Washington. While covering a land area less than one-half the size of Orlando's Walt Disney World, these downtowns accounted for 35 percent of national transit commuting.

Outside the Transit Legacy Cities: Automobile and Work at Home Country

So what about the 94 percent of US commuters who work outside the transit legacy cities? The answer is that the automobile dominates, and transit has been overtaken by working at home. In the suburban areas of metropolitan areas with transit legacy cities, the car carries 18 times as many people to work locations as transit. In the core municipalities of the 45 major metropolitan areas without legacy cities, cars carry 29 times as many commuters as transit, and 51 times as many in the suburbs. Outside the nation's major metropolitan areas, cars carry 82 times as many commuters as transit (Backgrounder Table 1)

Further, outside the transit legacy cities, working at home (including telecommuting) provides access to twenty percent more jobs than transit (Backgrounder Table 3).

An American Love Affair with the Automobile?

The enduring myth of the American love affair with automobile is countered by the huge transit market shares to city downtowns . For example, commuters to Manhattan are five times as likely to use transit as cars. On the other hand, commuters to the edge city of Parsippany, on the I-287 corridor in suburban New Jersey are 50 times as likely to use their cars as transit. Yet both employment centers serve the same labor market. The issue is not preferences, it is rather rational choice. It would be irrational for most people to commute to Manhattan by car, principally because of the traffic congestion and cost, particularly for parking. It would similarly be irrational for most people to commute to Parsippany by transit, because it either could not be done at all, or it would take too long.

Transit's work trip destination market share is an effective measure of its relevance to the market.

And lest anyone should counter that the answer is more money, consider this.

A Cost Not A Revenue Problem

Portland (with a core city that is not a legacy city) has long been held out as a model for improving transit. Yet, after billions of dollars in federal and local tax subsidies, more than 50 times as many people travel to work to suburban locations by car as by transit. More than five times as many work at home as use transit, and working at home costs taxpayers virtually nothing. Yet, despite all these billions, Portland's transit system is in crisis. Tri-Met's  Executive Director Neil McFarlane has warned of 70 percent service cuts over 12 years without substantial changes to union contracts.

Transit’s fundamental problem is not insufficient revenue but insufficient cost control. Since 1983, national transit expenditures have risen at an inflation-adjusted rate nine times that of its increase in commuters (Note 2). Even if costs were under control, it would be financially impossible to provide automobile-competitive transit throughout the modern urban area, as Professor Jean-Claude Ziv and I showed in our WCTRS paper (Megacities and Affluence: Transport and Land Use Considerations).

Celebrating Transit

Yet, beyond its inability to convert generous taxpayer subsidies into corresponding ridership increases, transit deserves credit for the large number of people it moves to jobs in the legacy cities. This success should be celebrated although it remains an impossible, prohibitively expensive, dream elsewhere.

Wendell Cox is a Visiting Professor, Conservatoire National des Arts et Metiers, Paris and the author of “War on the Dream: How Anti-Sprawl Policy Threatens the Quality of Life.”

----

Note 1: Each of the transit legacy cities has a lower population than the surrounding suburbs. This ranges from nearly 45 percent of the population in the suburbs of the New York metropolitan area to little more than 10 percent in Washington.

Note 2: Within the first 30 days of my time on the Los Angeles County Transportation Commission, I became convinced that transit's principal problem was cost control (see Toward More Prosperous Cities). This was then and today remains clear from the above-inflationary escalation of unit costs. Regrettably that trend continues today and has seriously impeded transit's ability to increase ridership.

-----

Photo: Downtown Philadelphia (by author)



















Comment viewing options

Select your preferred way to display the comments and click "Save settings" to activate your changes.

Legal Cities

Actually legal cities are their own issues for car owners and their pedestrians. But yes we should obey the traffic rules that will give a better Travel Experience and a safe drive always to us.

I like this post,And I guess

I like this post,And I guess that they having fun to read this post,they shall take a good site to make a information,thanks for sharing it to me.
how to get a girl that every guy wants

"This is just the

"This is just the information I am finding everywhere. Thanks for your blog, I just subscribe your blog. This is a nice blog. "
Ai wei wei

Cheers for this excellent. I

Cheers for this excellent. I was wondering whether you were planning of publishing similar posts to this. .Keep up the excellent articles!
Edward Bass Producer

iwin

gioi thieu he thong sieu thi mevabe cung cap do dung cho me va be, sua tuoi vinamilk 100% nguyen chat , sua bot Dumex chinh hang, sua Nestle cho tre em tai sieu thi sua bot lon nhat viet nam , ban co the xem them cac san pham sua Physiolac gia tot nhat hien nay , cung voi Bao moi choi game iwin online tren mobile

The transit based city racket

There are more points that count against the "transit based" city.

The Transit that happens to be capturing massive Federal subsidies, happens to be subsidising the strength of CBD's that already include the USA's highest-income employment sectors. It is utterly unjustified to provide heavily-subsidised mass transit for Wall Street. This is just another aspect of the successful rent-seeking that is ruining the USA. If there is anywhere that full cost recovery via fare revenue and/or special assessments on property is justified, it is Manhattan.

Meanwhile the intelligently-designed bus services that might actually provide mobility alternatives for poor people all over the US, have absolutely no-one in the powerful bureaucracies fighting FOR them. Why?

There is also the basic theories of transport flexibility and economic land rent, dating back to Robert Murray Haig in the 1920's, and incorporated in the theoretical work of luminaries like Alonso and Wingo. Michael Goldberg produced a very useful "general theory of transportation and economic land rent" in 1970.

It is patently obvious that the maximum-flexibility form of transport system minimises the level of economic rent captured by the owners of any one piece of land. Automobile based development in a genuine free market results in almost nil uplift in the economic land rent over and above rural levels, until the urban area has grown sufficiently further for the land to command a basic "location efficiency" premium. But urban expansion development based on a few fixed rail routes, or on strictly "planned" amounts of land beyond the fringe, always involves massive increases in economic land rent for those sites, and for all the land within the existing city (because rent is mostly derived from a location-efficiency premium over and above the fringe rent levels).

This is why the ratio of total total value of land to GDP is literally dozens or even hundreds of times higher in either a pre-automobility city or a growth-constrained one. This is NOT "amenity value" as many planners like to claim. The absurdity of this claim is illustrated by comparing the ratio of total value of land to GDP in UK cities, with US ones. Even the UK's LOWEST ratio cities, their equivalents of Detroit or Buffalo, have a higher ratio than NYC (which is the US's highest).

It is "economic rent", i.e. zero-sum wealth transfer via exploitation of distortions to the free market, NOT "amenity value" created by "planning". The alleged "amenity value" created by UK green-belt policies etc, is enjoyed by the top few percent of society only - it is urban hell for everyone else. And laughter all the way to the bank for the rentier class - "big property" and the finance sector.

Cox and Ziv: very good paper

Wendell, I never knew about THIS paper before, it is very good:

".....it would be financially impossible to provide automobile-competitive transit throughout the modern urban area, as Professor Jean-Claude Ziv and I showed in our WCTRS paper (Megacities and Affluence: Transport and Land Use Considerations)....."

http://www.publicpurpose.com/ut-wctrs2007.pdf

I recommend it to everyone else who is reading this.

Các khoản đầu tư

Các khoản đầu tư hàng trăm triệu USD để mở rộng quy mô nuôi bò sữa của Vinamilk, TH, Nutifood hay FrieslandCampina đang sửa chữa hướng “phát triển ...
sua nutifood 123

nutifood khuyến mãi
nutifood tuyển dụng\
sua bot nuti 456

nutifood grow plus
nutifood việt nam
sữa nutifood
nutifood pedia plus
khuyến mại sữa nutifood

giá sữa nutifood
dutch lady